A Blog by Jonathan Low

 

Apr 6, 2014

Intellectual Capital's Value in a Post-Scarcity Economy

All professions are conspiracies against the laity. British playwright George Bernard Shaw made that observation in 1906 and our behavior in the last hundred plus years has done little to disprove it.

The epic legal battles between Samsung (standing in for Google) and Apple as well as those between various other digital combatants attempting to use legal means to close a barn door never meant to be shut may be signalling the end of the beginning.

We have wrested as much value as we can from this latest stage of technological development and are now witnessing the 21st century's version of The Great Game. That was the diplomatic and military scramble to secure both markets and raw materials at the end of the 19th and early 20th centuries. Let us aver that the competitors got a bit carried away and ended up fighting World War I - and later World War II in order to sort it all out.

While the latest version promises, so far, to be altogether less bloodthirsty, if no less expensive, the issue is still about scarcity and position. As the following article explains, businesses and governments are vainly attempting to reinforce whatever scarcity remains so that they can harvest whatever latent value survives.

The only ones likely to get rich are the intermediaries, but given what disintermediation has cost them, there is some ironic justice in that. The future lies in recognition of a shared legacy of innovation from to which many contributed and from which many have benefited. JL

Mark Lemley comments in the Bangkok Post:

IP rights are designed to artificially replicate scarcity where it would not otherwise exist.
Things are valuable because they are scarce. The more abundant they become, they cheaper they become. But a series of technological changes is under way that promises to end scarcity as we know it for a variety of goods and services. The internet is the most obvious example, because the change there is furthest along. The internet has reduced the cost of production and distribution of informational content effectively to zero. In many cases it has also dramatically reduced the cost of producing that content. And it has changed the way in which information is distributed, separating the creators of content from the distributors.
More recently, new technologies promise to do for a variety of physical goods and even services what the internet has already done for information. 3D printers can manufacture physical goods based on any digital design. Synthetic biology has automated the manufacture not just of copies of existing genetic sequences but any custom-made gene sequence, allowing anyone who wants to create a gene sequence of their own to upload the sequence to a company that will “print” it using the basic building blocks of genetics. 
Advances in robotics offer the prospect that many of the services humans now provide can be provided free of charge by general-purpose machines that can be programmed to perform a variety of complex functions. While none of these technologies are nearly as far along as the internet, they share two essential characteristics with the internet: they radically reduce the cost of production and distribution of things, and they separate the informational content of those things (the design) from their manufacture. 
Combine these four developments — the internet, 3D printing, robotics and synthetic biology — and it is entirely plausible to envision a not-too-distant world in which most things that people want can be downloaded and created on site for very little money. 
The role of intellectual property (IP) in such a world is both controverted and critically important. IP rights are designed to artificially replicate scarcity where it would not otherwise exist. In its simplest form, IP law takes public goods that would otherwise be available to all and artificially restricts their distribution. It makes ideas scarce, because then we can bring them into the economy and charge for them, and economics knows how to deal with scarce things.
So on one view — the classical view of IP law — a world in which all the value resides in information is a world in which we need IP everywhere, controlling rights over everything, or no one will get paid to create. That has been the response of IP law to the internet so far. That response is a problem for a couple of reasons. First, it doesn’t seem to be working. By disaggregating creation, production, and distribution, the internet democratised access to content. Copyright owners have been unable to stop a flood of piracy with 50,000 lawsuits, a host of new and increasingly draconian laws, and a well-funded public education campaign that starts in elementary school. Second, even if we could use IP to rein in all this low-cost production and distribution of stuff, we may not want to. The point of IP has always been, not to raise prices and reduce consumption for its own sake, but to encourage people to create things when they otherwise wouldn’t. More and more evidence casts doubt on the link between IP and creation, however. Empirical evidence suggests that offering money may actually stifle rather than drive creativity among individuals. Economic evidence suggests that quite often it is competition, not the lure of monopoly, that drives corporate innovation. The internet may have spawned unprecedented piracy, but it has also given rise to the creation of more works of all types than ever before in history, often by multiple orders of magnitude. Far from necessitating more IP protection, then, the development of cost-reducing technologies may actually weaken the case for IP. If people are intrinsically motivated to create, as they seem to be, the easier it is to create and distribute content, the more content is likely to be available even in the absence of IP. And if the point of IP is to encourage either the creation or the distribution of that content, cost-reducing technologies may actually mean we have less, not more, need for IP. 
IP rights are a form of government regulation of market entry and market prices. We regulated all sorts of industries in the 20th century, from airlines to trucking to telephones to electric power, often... because we couldn’t conceive of how the industry could survive without the government preventing entry by competitors. Towards the end of that century, however, we experimented with deregulation, and it turned out that the market could provide many of those services better in the absence of government regulation. The same thing may turn out to be true of IP regulation in the 21st century. We didn’t get rid of all regulation by any means, and we won’t get rid of all IP. But we came to understand that the free market, not government control over entry, is the right default position in the absence of a persuasive justification for limiting that market. The elimination of scarcity will put substantial pressure on the law to do the same with IP. A world without scarcity requires a major rethinking of economics, much as the decline of the agrarian economy did in the 19th century. How will our economy function in a world in which most of the things we produce are cheap or free? We have lived with scarcity for so long that it is hard even to begin to think about the transition to a post-scarcity economy. IP has allowed us to cling to scarcity as an organising principle in a world that no longer demands it. But it will no more prevent the transition than agricultural price supports kept us all farmers.We need a post-scarcity economics, one that accepts rather than resists the new opportunities technology will offer us. Developing that economics is the great task of the 21st century.



0 comments:

Post a Comment